THE COMPUTER AND THE
MARKET
OSKAR LANGE
I
In my essay I refuted
the Hayek—Robbins argument by showing how a market mechanism could be
established in a socialist economy which would lead to the solution of the
simultaneous equations by means of an empirical procedure of trial and error.
Starting with an arbitrary set of prices, the price is raised whenever demand
exceeds supply and lowered whenever the opposite is the case. Through such a
process of tatonnements, first
described by Walras, the final equilibrium prices are gradually reached. These
are the prices satisfying the system of simultaneous equations. It was assumed
without question that the tatonnement process
in fact converges to the system of equilibrium prices.
Were I to rewrite my
essay today my task would be much simpler. My answer to Hayek and Robbins would
be: so what’s the trouble?
Let us put the
simultaneous equations on an electronic computer and we shall obtain the
solution in less than a second. The market process with its cumbersome tatonnements
appears old-fashioned. Indeed, it may be considered as a computing device of
the preelectronic age.
II
The same process can
be implemented by an electronic analogue machine which simulates the iteration
process implied in the tátonnements of
the market mechanism. Such an electronic analogue (servo-mechanism) simulates
the working of the market. This statement, however, may be reversed: the
market simulates the electronic analogue computer. In other words, the market
may be considered as a computer sui
generis which serves to solve a system of simultaneous equations. It
operates like an analogue machine: a servo-mechanism based on the feedback
principle. The market may be considered as one of the oldest historical devices
for solving simultaneous equations. The interesting thing is that the solving
mechanism operates not via a physical but via a social process. It turns out
that the social processes as well may serve as a basis for the operation of
feedback devices leading to the solution of equations by iteration.
III
It may be interesting
to compare the relative merits of the market and of the computer in a socialist
economy. The computer has the undoubted advantage of much greater speed. The
market is a cumbersome and slow-working servo-mechanism. Its iteration process
operates with considerable time-lags and oscillations and may not be convergent
at all. This is shown by cobweb cycles, inventory and other reinvestment cycles
as well as by the general business cycle. Thus the Walrasian tatonnements
are full of unpleasant fluctuations and may also prove to be divergent. In
this respect the electronic computer shows an unchallenged superiority. It
works with enormous speed, does not produce fluctuations in real economic
processes and the convergence of its iterations is assured by its very
construction.
Another disadvantage
of the market as a servo-mechanism is that its iterations cause income effects.
Any change in prices causes gains and losses to various groups of people. To the
management of a socialist economy this creates various social problems connected
with these gains and losses. Furthermore, it may mobilise conservative
resistance to the iteration process involved in the use of the market as a
servo-mechanism.
All this, however,
does not mean that the market has not its relative merits. First of all, even
the most powerful electronic computers have a limited capacity. There may be
(and there are) economic processes so complex in terms of the number of
commodities and the type of equations involved that no computer can tackle them.
Or it may be too costly to construct computers of such large capacity. In such
cases nothing remains but to use the old-fashioned market servo-mechanism which
has a much broader working capacity.
Secondly, the market
is institutionally embodied in the present socialist economy. In all socialist
countries (with the exception of certain periods when rationing was used)
consumers’ goods are distributed to the population by means of the market.
Here, the market is an existing social institution and it is useless to apply an
alternative accounting device. The electronic computer can be applied for
purposes of prognostication but the computed forecasts have later to be
confirmed by the actual working of the market.
An important
limitation of the market is that it treats the accounting problem only in static
terms, i.e. as an equilibrium problem. It does not provide a sufficient
foundation for the solution of growth and development problems. In particular,
it does not provide an adequate basis for long-term economic planning. For
planning economic development long-term investments have to be taken out of the
market mechanism and based on judgment of developmental economic policy. This is
because present prices reflect present data, whereas investment changes data by
creating new incomes, new technical conditions of production and frequently also
by creating new wants (the creation of a television industry creates the demand
for television sets, not the other way round). In other words, investment
changes the conditions of supply and demand which determine equilibrium prices.
This holds for capitalism as well as for socialism.
For the reasons
indicated, planning of long-term economic development as a rule is based on
overall considerations of economic policy rather than upon calculations based on
current prices. However, the theory and practice of mathematical (linear and
non-linear) programming makes it possible to introduce strict economic
accounting into this process. After setting up an objective function (for
instance, maximizing the increase of national income over a certain period) and
certain constraints, future shadow prices can be calculated. These shadow prices
serve as an instrument of economic accounting in long-term development plans.
Actual market equilibrium prices do not suffic here, knowledge of the programmed
future shadow prices is needed.
Mathematical
programming turns out to be an essential instrument of optimal long-term economic planning. In so far as this involves the
solution of large numbers of equations and inequalities the electronic computer
is indispensable. Mathematical programming assisted by electronic computers
becomes the fundamental instrument of long-term economic planning, as well as of
solving dynamic economic problems of a more limited scope. Here, the electronic
computer does not replace the market. It fulfils a function which the market
never was able to perform.
Footnotes:
1 The Review of
Economic Studies, London 1936 and 1937. Reprinted in O. Lange and F. M. Taylor, On
the Economic Theory of Socialism, edited by B. E. Lippincott, Minneapolis
1938.
2 Cf. Josef Steindl,
Servo-mechanisms and Controllers in Economic Theory and Policy, in On
Political Economy and Econometrics, Essays in Honour of Oskar Lange, Warsaw
1964, pp. 552— 554 in particular.